Feeds:
Entradas
Comentarios

Archive for mayo 2009

Pregunta de ingenio

De esta no sé la respuesta:

Los cajeros automáticos tienen un botón que libera la puerta, o a veces un lector de tarjeta magnética (que abre con cualquier tarjeta). Alguien tiene idea de para que demonios sirve ese botón????

Read Full Post »

Burocracias

En los últimos día tuve que hacer varios trámites. Algunos, como el pasaporte, fueron bastante rápidos y eficientes. En otros casos, como la credencial de mi hijo, mientras esperaba, fantaseaba con comprar una ametralladora y … mejor no doy ideas.

Pero sí voy a dar una idea constructiva. La realidad es que a gran parte de los funcionarios les importa tres cominos si yo tengo que ir 8 veces, o esperar dos horas para que me digan que tengo que volver mañana. La idea es premiar a cada organismo que reduce el tiempo y dinero que le hace perder a los ciudadanos.

Me imagino algo así. Primero se contrata una consultora que estima cuanto le cuesta a la sociedad un trámite. Por ejemplo, sacar una partida de nacimiento te implica ir una vez a sacar hora (si no es urgente), y otra vez a recibir la partida. Eso implica dos viajes de ida y vuelta en bus, más dos horas de tiempo perdido en transporte (dos viajes de ida y vuelta de media hora), más dos horas de tiempo de espera. El PBI per capita y por hora trabajada del Uruguay son más o menos $125. O sea que ese trámite le cuesta a la sociedad $60 + $125*4, que son $560 (23 dólares aprox).

Si 500.000 personas sacan una partida de nacimiento por año, la sociedad está pagando 11 millones de dólares por año por los trámites de la partida de nacimiento. Eso además de lo que cuestan los sueldos, edificio, estructura, etc.

Mi propuesta es decirle al organismo que si le ahorran tiempo y costos a la gente, se quedan con una parte del ahorro para los funcionarios (una única vez), y una parte la pueden usar para las inversiones que hayan sido necesarias. Por ejemplo, si implementan un sistema de atención telefónica que reduce el costo a la sociedad en 5 millones de dólares, tienen 500.000 dólares anuales para el costo de las centrales, etc., y otros 2 millones por única vez para dar premios a los funcionarios, etc.

Read Full Post »

Una blogera de Silicon Valley esta escribiendo un post sobre social networks en el mundo globalizado y me pidio que le mande info sobre Social Nertworks de latinoamerica y Espana.

La verdad es que confieso que no estoy muy actualizado,lo unico que uso es facebook y linkedin, se de la fuerza que esta teniendo Sonico y algo de Hi5, y obviamente la presencia de Orkut en Brasil

Si pueden mandarme aportes les agradezco

— pablo

Read Full Post »

Los secretos de Googlenomics

Este articulo salio en la Wired y me lo envio Thomas (gracias Thomas), creo que es super interesante asi que lo publico aca:

(no encuentro el link al original, si alguno lo encuentra avise asi lo pongo, aca esta, gentilezas de Pablo y Juan Pechiar)

 

WIRED MAGAZINE: 17.06

Secret of Googlenomics: Data-Fueled Recipe Brews Profitability

By Steven Levy
05.22.09

As the amount of data at Google’s disposal grows, the opportunities to exploit it multiply.

In the midst of financial apocalypse, the gadflies and gurus of the global marketplace are gathered at the San Francisco Hilton for theannual meeting of the American Economics Association. The mood is similar to a seismologist convention in the wake of the Big One. Yet surprisingly, one of the most popular sessions has nothing to do with toxic assets, derivatives, or unemployment curves.
«I’m going to talk about online auctions,» says Hal Varian, the session’s first speaker. Varian is a lanky 62-year-old professor at UC Berkeley’s Haas School of Business and School of Information, but these days he’s best known as Google’s chief economist. This morning’s crowd hasn’t come for predictions about the credit market; they want to hear about Google’s secret sauce.

Varian is an expert on what may be the most successful business idea in history: AdWords, Google’s unique method for selling online advertising. AdWords analyzes every Google search to determine which advertisers get each of up to 11 «sponsored links» on every results page. It’s the world’s biggest, fastest auction, a never-ending, automated, self-service version of Tokyo’s boisterous Tsukiji fish market, and it takes place, Varian says, «every time you search.» He never mentions how much revenue advertising brings in. But Google is a public company, so anyone can find the number: It was $21 billion last year.

His talk quickly becomes technical. There’s the difference between the Generalized Second Price auction model and the Vickrey-Clark-Groves alternative. Game theory takes a turn; so does the Nash Equilibrium. Terms involving the c-word—as in clicks—get tossed around like beach balls at a summer rock festival. Clickthrough rate. Cost per click. Supply curve of clicks. The audience is enthralled.

During the question-and-answer period, a man wearing a camel-colored corduroy blazer raises his hand. «Let me understand this,» he begins, half skeptical, half unsure. «You say that an auction happens every time a search takes place? That would mean millions of times a day!»

Varian smiles. «Millions,» he says, «is actually quite an understatement.»

Why does Google even need a chief economist? The simplest reason is that the company is an economy unto itself. The ad auction, marinated in that special sauce, is a seething laboratory of fiduciary forensics, with customers ranging from giant multinationals to dorm-room entrepreneurs, all billed by the world’s largest micropayment system.

Google depends on economic principles to hone what has become the search engine of choice for more than 60 percent of all Internet surfers, and the company uses auction theory to grease the skids of its own operations. All these calculations require an army of math geeks, algorithms of Ramanujanian complexity, and a sales force more comfortable with whiteboard markers than fairway irons.

Varian, an upbeat, avuncular presence at the Googleplex in Mountain View, California, serves as the Adam Smith of the new discipline of Googlenomics. His job is to provide a theoretical framework for Google’s business practices while leading a team of quants to enforce bottom-line discipline, reining in the more propellerhead propensities of the company’s dominant engineering culture.

Googlenomics actually comes in two flavors: macro and micro. The macroeconomic side involves some of the company’s seemingly altruistic behavior, which often baffles observers. Why does Google give away products like its browser, its apps, and the Android operating system for mobile phones? Anything that increases Internet use ultimately enriches Google, Varian says. And since using the Web without using Google is like dining at In-N-Out without ordering a hamburger, more eyeballs on the Web lead inexorably to more ad sales for Google.

The microeconomics of Google is more complicated. Selling ads doesn’t generate only profits; it also generates torrents of data about users’ tastes and habits, data that Google then sifts and processes in order to predict future consumer behavior, find ways to improve its products, and sell more ads. This is the heart and soul of Googlenomics. It’s a system of constant self-analysis: a data-fueled feedback loop that defines not only Google’s future but the future of anyone who does business online.

When the American Economics Association meets next year, the financial crisis may still be topic A. But one of the keynote speakers has already been chosen: Googlenomist Hal Varian.

Ironically, economics was a distant focus in the first days of Google. After Larry Page and Sergey Brin founded the company in 1998, they channeled their energy into its free search product and left much of the business planning to a 22-year-old Stanford graduate named Salar Kamangar, Google’s ninth employee. The early assumption was that although ads would be an important source of revenue, licensing search technology and selling servers would be just as lucrative. Page and Brin also believed that ads should be useful and welcome—not annoying intrusions. Kamangar and another early Googler, Eric Veach, set out to implement that ideal. Neither had a background in business or economics. Kamangar had been a biology major, and Veach’s field of study was computer science.

Google’s ads were always plain blocks of text relevant to the search query. But at first, there were two kinds. Ads at the top of the page were sold the old-fashioned way, by a crew of human beings headquartered largely in New York City. Salespeople wooed big customers over dinner, explaining what keywords meant and what the prices were. Advertisers were then billed by the number of user views, or impressions, regardless of whether anyone clicked on the ad. Down the right side were other ads that smaller businesses could buy directly online. The first of these, forlive mail-order lobsters, was sold in 2000, just minutes after Google deployed a link reading SEE YOUR AD HERE.
But as the business grew, Kamangar and Veach decided to price the slots on the side of the page by means of an auction. Not an eBay-style auction that unfolds over days or minutes as bids are raised or abandoned, but a huge marketplace of virtual auctions in which sealed bids are submitted in advance and winners are determined algorithmically in fractions of a second. Google hoped that millions of small and medium companies would take part in the market, so it was essential that the process be self-service. Advertisers bid on search terms, or keywords, but instead of bidding on the price per impression, they were bidding on a price they were willing to pay each time a user clicked on the ad. (The bid would be accompanied by a budget of how many clicks the advertiser was willing to pay for.) The new system was called AdWords Select, while the ads at the top of the page, with prices still set by humans, was renamed AdWords Premium.

One key innovation was that all the sidebar slots on the results page were sold off in a single auction. (Compare that to an early pioneer of auction-driven search ads, Overture, which held a separate auction for each slot.) The problem with an all-at-once auction, however, was that advertisers might be inclined to lowball their bids to avoid the sucker’s trap of paying a huge amount more than the guy just below them on the page. So the Googlers decided that the winner of each auction would pay the amount (plus a penny) of the bid from the advertiser with the next-highest offer. (If Joe bids $10, Alice bids $9, and Sue bids $6, Joe gets the top slot and pays $9.01. Alice gets the next slot for $6.01, and so on.) Since competitors didn’t have to worry about costly overbidding errors, the paradoxical result was that it encouraged higher bids.

«Eric Veach did the math independently,» Kamangar says. «We found out along the way that second-price auctions had existed in other forms in the past and were used at one time in Treasury auctions.» (Another crucial innovation had to do with ad quality, but more on that later.)

Google’s homemade solution to its ad problem impressed even Paul Milgrom, the Stanford economist who is to auction theory what Letitia Baldridge is to etiquette. «I’ve begun to realize that Google somehow stumbled on a level of simplification in ad auctions that was not included before,» he says. And applying a variation on second-price auctions wasn’t just a theoretical advance. «Google immediately started getting higher prices for advertising than Overture was getting.»

Google hired Varian in May 2002, a few months after implementing the auction- based version of AdWords. The offer came about when Google’s then-new CEO, Eric Schmidt, ran into Varian at the Aspen Institute and they struck up a conversation about Internet issues. Schmidt was with Larry Page, who was pushing his own notions about how some of the big problems in business and science could be solved by using computation and analysis on an unprecedented scale. Varian remembers thinking, «Why did Eric bring his high-school nephew?»

Schmidt, whose father was an economist, invited Varian to spend a day or two a week at Google. On his first visit, Varian asked Schmidt what he should do. «Why don’t you take a look at the ad auction?» Schmidt said.

Google had already developed the basics of AdWords, but there was still plenty of tweaking to do, and Varian was uniquely qualified to «take a look.» As head of the information school at UC Berkeley and coauthor (with Carl Shapiro) of a popular book called Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy, he was already the go-to economist on ecommerce.

At the time, most online companies were still selling advertising the way it was done in the days of Mad Men. But Varian saw immediately that Google’s ad business was less like buying traditional spots and more like computer dating. «The theory was Google as yenta—matchmaker,» he says. He also realized there was another old idea underlying the new approach: A 1983 paper by Harvard economist Herman Leonard described using marketplace mechanisms to assign job candidates to slots in a corporation, or students to dorm rooms. It was called a two-sided matching market. «The mathematical structure of the Google auction,» Varian says, «is the same as those two-sided matching markets.»

Varian tried to understand the process better by applying game theory. «I think I was the first person to do that,» he says. After just a few weeks at Google, he went back to Schmidt. «It’s amazing!» Varian said. «You’ve managed to design an auction perfectly.»

To Schmidt, who had been at Google barely a year, this was an incredible relief. «Remember, this was when the company had 200 employees and no cash,» he says. «All of a sudden we realized we were in the auction business.»

It wasn’t long before the success of AdWords Select began to dwarf that of its sister system, the more traditional AdWords Premium. Inevitably, Veach and Kamangar argued that all the ad slots should be auctioned off. In search, Google had already used scale, power, and clever algorithms to change the way people accessed information. By turning over its sales process entirely to an auction-based system, the company could similarly upend the world of advertising, removing human guesswork from the equation.

The move was risky. Going ahead with the phaseout—nicknamed Premium Sunset—meant giving up campaigns that were selling for hundreds of thousands of dollars, for the unproven possibility that the auction process would generate even bigger sums. «We were going to erase a huge part of the company’s revenue,» says Tim Armstrong, then head of direct sales in the US. (This March, Armstrong left Google to become AOL’s new chair and CEO.) «Ninety-nine percent of companies would have said, ‘Hold on, don’t make that change.’ But we had Larry, Sergey, and Eric saying, ‘Let’s go for it.'»

News of the switch jacked up the Maalox consumption among Google’s salespeople. Instead of selling to corporate giants, their job would now be to get them to place bids in an auction? «We thought it was a little half-cocked,» says Jeff Levick, an early leader of the Google sales team. The young company wasn’t getting rid of its sales force (though the system certainly helped Google run with far fewer salespeople than a traditional media company) but was asking them to get geekier, helping big customers shape online strategies as opposed to simply selling ad space.

Levick tells a story of visiting three big customers to inform them of the new system: «The guy in California almost threw us out of his office and told us to fuck ourselves. The guy in Chicago said, ‘This is going to be the worst business move you ever made.’ But the guy in Massachusetts said, ‘I trust you.'»

That client knew math, says Levick, whose secret weapon was the numbers. When the data was crunched—and Google worked hard to give clients the tools needed to run the numbers themselves—advertisers saw that the new system paid off for them, too.

AdWords was such a hit that Google went auction-crazy. The company used auctions to place ads on other Web sites (that program was dubbed AdSense). «But the really gutsy move,» Varian says, «was using it in the IPO.» In 2004, Google used a variation of a Dutch auction for its IPO; Brin and Page loved that the process leveled the playing field between small investors and powerful brokerage houses. And in 2008, the company couldn’t resist participating in the FCC’s auction to reallocate portions of the radio spectrum.

Google even uses auctions for internal operations, like allocating servers among its various business units. Since moving a product’s storage and computation to a new data center is disruptive, engineers often put it off. «I suggested we run an auction similar to what the airlines do when they oversell a flight. They keep offering bigger vouchers until enough customers give up their seats,» Varian says. «In our case, we offer more machines in exchange for moving to new servers. One group might do it for 50 new ones, another for 100, and another won’t move unless we give them 300. So we give them to the lowest bidder—they get their extra capacity, and we get computation shifted to the new data center.»

The transition to an all-auction sales model was a milestone for Google, ensuring that its entire revenue engine would run with the same computer-science fervor as its search operation. Now, when Google recruits alpha geeks, it is just as likely to have them focus on AdWords as on search or apps.

The across-the-board emphasis on engineering, mathematical formulas, and data-mining has made Google a new kind of company. But to fully understand why, you have to go back and look under AdWords’ hood.

Most people think of the Google ad auction as a straightforward affair. In fact, there’s a key component that few users know about and even sophisticated advertisers don’t fully understand. The bids themselves are only a part of what ultimately determines the auction winners. The other major determinant is something called the quality score. This metric strives to ensure that the ads Google shows on its results page are true, high-caliber matches for what users are querying. If they aren’t, the whole system suffers and Google makes less money.

Google determines quality scores by calculating multiple factors, including the relevance of the ad to the specific keyword or keywords, the quality of the landing page the ad is linked to, and, above all, the percentage of times users actually click on a given ad when it appears on a results page. (Other factors, Google won’t even discuss.) There’s also a penalty invoked when the ad quality is too low—in such cases, the company slaps a minimum bid on the advertiser. Google explains that this practice—reviled by many companies affected by it—protects users from being exposed to irrelevant or annoying ads that would sour people on sponsored links in general. Several lawsuitshave been filed by would-be advertisers who claim that they are victims of an arbitrary process by a quasi monopoly.

You can argue about fairness, but arbitrary it ain’t. To figure out the quality score, Google needs to estimate in advance how many users will click on an ad. That’s very tricky, especially since we’re talking about billions of auctions. But since the ad model depends on predicting clickthroughs as perfectly as possible, the company must quantify and analyze every twist and turn of the data. Susan Wojcicki, who oversees Google’s advertising, refers to it as «the physics of clicks.»

During Varian’s second summer in Mountain View, when he was still coming in only a day or two a week, he asked a recently hired computer scientist from Stanford named Diane Tang to create the Google equivalent of the Consumer Price Index, called the Keyword Pricing Index. «Instead of a basket of goods like diapers and beer and doughnuts, we have keywords,» says Tang, who is known internally as the Queen of Clicks.

The Keyword Pricing Index is a reality check. It alerts Google to any anomalous price bubbles, a sure sign that an auction isn’t working properly. Categories are ranked by the cost per click that advertisers generally have to pay, weighted by distribution, and then separated into three bundles: high cap, mid cap, and low cap. «The high caps are very competitive keywords, like ‘flowers’ and ‘hotels,'» Tang says. In the mid-cap realm you have keywords that may vary seasonally—the price to place ads alongside results for «snowboarding» skyrockets during the winter. Low caps like «Massachusetts buggy whips» are the stuff of long tails.

Tang’s index is just one example of a much broader effort. As the amount of data at the company’s disposal grows, the opportunities to exploit it multiply, which ends up further extending the range and scope of the Google economy. So it’s utterly essential to calculate correctly the quality scores that prop up AdWords.

«The people working for me are generally econometricians—sort of a cross between statisticians and economists,» says Varian, who moved to Google full-time in 2007 (he’s on leave from Berkeley) and leads two teams, one of them focused on analysis.

«Google needs mathematical types that have a rich tool set for looking for signals in noise,» says statistician Daryl Pregibon, who joined Google in 2003 after 23 years as a top scientist at Bell Labs and AT&T Labs. «The rough rule of thumb is one statistician for every 100 computer scientists.»

Keywords and click rates are their bread and butter. «We are trying to understand the mechanisms behind the metrics,» says Qing Wu, one of Varian’s minions. His specialty is forecasting, so now he predicts patterns of queries based on the season, the climate, international holidays, even the time of day. «We have temperature data, weather data, and queries data, so we can do correlation and statistical modeling,» Wu says. The results all feed into Google’s backend system, helping advertisers devise more-efficient campaigns.

To track and test their predictions, Wu and his colleagues use dozens of onscreen dashboards that continuously stream information, a sort of Bloomberg terminal for the Googlesphere. Wu checks obsessively to see whether reality is matching the forecasts: «With a dashboard, you can monitor the queries, the amount of money you make, how many advertisers you have, how many keywords they’re bidding on, what the rate of return is for each advertiser.»

Wu calls Google «the barometer of the world.» Indeed, studying the clicks is like looking through a window with a panoramic view of everything. You can see the change of seasons—clicks gravitating toward skiing and heavy clothes in winter, bikinis and sunscreen in summer—and you can track who’s up and down in pop culture. Most of us remember news events from television or newspapers; Googlers recall them as spikes in their graphs. «One of the big things a few years ago was the SARS epidemic,» Tang says. Wu didn’t even have to read the papers to know about the financial meltdown—he saw the jump in people Googling for gold. And since prediction and analysis are so crucial to AdWords, every bit of data, no matter how seemingly trivial, has potential value.

Since Google hired Varian, other companies, like Yahoo, have decided that they, too, must have a chief economist heading a division that scrutinizes auctions, dashboards, and econometric models to fine-tune their business plan. In 2007, Harvard economist Susan Athey was surprised to get a summons to Redmond to meet with Steve Ballmer. «That’s a call you take,» she says. Athey spent last year working in Microsoft’s Cambridge, Massachusetts, office.

Can the rest of the world be far behind? Although Eric Schmidt doesn’t think it will happen as quickly as some believe, he does think that Google-style auctions are applicable to all sorts of transactions. The solution to the glut in auto inventory? Put the entire supply of unsold cars up for bid. That’ll clear out the lot. Housing, too: «People use auctions now in cases of distress, like auctioning a house when there are no buyers,» Schmidt says. «But you can imagine a situation in which it was a normal and routine way of doing things.»

Varian believes that a new era is dawning for what you might call the datarati—and it’s all about harnessing supply and demand. «What’s ubiquitous and cheap?» Varian asks. «Data.» And what is scarce? The analytic ability to utilize that data. As a result, he believes that the kind of technical person who once would have wound up working for a hedge fund on Wall Street will now work at a firm whose business hinges on making smart, daring choices—decisions based on surprising results gleaned from algorithmic spelunking and executed with the confidence that comes from really doing the math.

It’s a satisfying development for Varian, a guy whose career as an economist was inspired by a sci-fi novel he read in junior high. «In Isaac Asimov’s first Foundation Trilogy, there was a character who basically constructed mathematical models of society, and I thought this was a really exciting idea. When I went to college, I looked around for that subject. It turned out to be economics.» Varian is telling this story from his pied-è0-Plex, where he sometimes stays during the week to avoid driving the 40-some miles from Google headquarters to his home in the East Bay. It happens to be the ranch-style house, which Google now owns, where Brin and Page started the company.

There’s a wild contrast between this sparsely furnished residence and what it has spawned—dozens of millionaire geeks, billions of auctions, and new ground rules for businesses in a data-driven society that is far weirder than the one Asimov envisioned nearly 60 years ago. What could be more baffling than a capitalist corporation that gives away its best services, doesn’t set the prices for the ads that support it, and turns away customers because their ads don’t measure up to its complex formulas? Varian, of course, knows that his employer’s success is not the result of inspired craziness but of an early recognition that the Internet rewards fanatical focus on scale, speed, data analysis, and customer satisfaction. (A bit of auction theory doesn’t hurt, either.) Today we have a name for those rules: Googlenomics. Learn them, or pay the price.

Senior writer Steven Levy (steven_levy@wired.com) wrote about the Kryptos sculpture at CIA headquarters in issue 17.05.

Read Full Post »

Puzzle

Llega un nuevo puzzle al blog… bueno, en realidad no es un nuevo puzzle, casi todos los puzzles son muy viejos, pero igual. Este da para divertirse un poco en reuniones sociales de todo tipo.

Tomá un corcho y ponelo en un vaso de agua. Al cabo de algunos segundos, el corcho se va a ir hacia el borde del vaso. El desafío es cómo hacer para que el corcho quede en el medio del vaso, es decir, sin tocar el borde.

Como siempre, la solución en un par de días en los comentarios.

Read Full Post »

FIA 2009

Estos dias fue el FIA 2009, en algun comentario me preguntaron que opinaba, la verdad es que me abstuve de opinar ya que no estaba lo suficientemente informado, a diferencia del 2008 donde estuve involucrado en la organizacion, esta vez estuve al margen.

La impresion que tenia antes del evento es que no se la habia hecho la difusion correcta, se hizo si mucha difusion en medios y carteleria, pero yo no vi mucho PR respecto al contenido, no quedaba claro a quien iba dirigida, cual era el foco etc (puede ser que si haya existido y yo me la perdi entre que estaba al mango con trabajo, y hastiado de leer y escuchar noticias sobre la violencia en el deporte y la campana politica, lo cual seguramente me llevo a leer poca prensa).

Me di un par de vueltas por el evento, y tengo que decir que me sorprendio la alta concurrencia, el domingo, dia de clasico (me reservo los comentarios para no enojar a los manyas….), habia mucha, mucha gente en el Radisson.

Alguien tiene algun comentario bueno o malo sobre el FIA 2009?

Read Full Post »

El otro dia se publico que Ence finalmente vendio sus activos. Me sonaba que habiamos escrito algo al respecto en este blog, asi que me puse a buscar, y encontre este post de Sergio de Octubre 2008:

 

https://pablobrenner.wordpress.com/2008/10/25/un-par-de-predicciones/

Un par de predicciones

Archivado en: economia — sfogel @ 11:01 am Editar

Hace un par de días un amigo me hablaba con gran optimismo sobre Uruguay, el crecimiento del PBI, lo bien que estaba todo y como la crisis no iba a impactar en el país. Siguiendo la teoría de mi padre, acerca de que un optimista no es más que un pesimista mal informado, van un par de predicciones mías.

1) Las plantas de celulosa de Ence y Portucel no se realizan. No las van a cancelar, pero por ahora no van a invertir. Sí, van a seguir moviendo tierra, y haciendo alguna cosa, pero no van a invertir con fuerza. En qué me baso? En dos factores. Primero y menos importante, el precio de la pulpa se cayó, y no hay certeza de que vaya a subir. Segundo, estas empresas no tienen 1000 millones de dólares en el banco, esperando para ser invertidos en Uruguay. Para hacer una inversión de esa naturaleza, necesitan financiamiento externo, ya sea tomando un crédito o emitiendo acciones. Las dos alternativas están cerradas.

2) El crecimiento en el 2009 va a ser entre 0% y 2%. No hay manera de sostener un crecimiento del 6% con un mundo en recesión, los precios de los commodities en picada y crédito inexistente. Puede ser que el primer trimestre del 2009 aún tenga un crecimiento importante sobre el trimestre correspondiente del 2008, por un efecto de arrastre, pero después se viene en picada.

Acá seguimos de fiesta. Alguien se llevó todo el alcohol, pero no nos importó. Paró la música, y seguimos bailando. Antes o después nos vamos a dar cuenta que la fiesta se terminó.

La verdad que le pego bastante bien a las dos, asi que aca va el reconocimiento.

Personalmente creo que es bueno que Ence se vaya, me parece que los planes de Stora Enzo y Arauca van a ser mas serios, aunque seguramente van a esperar a que pase la tormenta, y la gente de Conchillas lamentablemente la vio pasar

Ahora, Sergio, contanos como sigue, cuando se termina la crisis en USA? quien gana las elecciones? 

Read Full Post »

Las ultimas semanas fueron bastante moviditas, y como se dieron cuenta no tuve mucho tiempo para postear.

Entre otras cosas se me paso anunciar la 5ta inversion de Prosperitas: CPG Soft.

CPG-Soft, liderada por Fernando Lazcano y Quino Galiana,  es una de las empresas derivadas de la antigua Solur, y se especializan en soluciones para la gestion de ventas, distribucion y logisitca (lo que se engloba en «supply-chain»), y tienen algunos clientes bastante importantes como CCU en Chile (la principal cervecera).

A nuestro entender en el tema de Supply Chain y logistica todavia existe una gran necesidad de mercado, y hay mucho espacio para soluciones innovadoras, muchas de las soluciones existentes en el primer mundo asumen un mundo de negocios demasiado ordenado que difiere en mucho de la realidad de los mercados emergentes. Por ejemplo, un software americano o europeo puede asumir que el pedido del cliente llega electronicamente y el pago es con transferencia bancaria, la realidad de nuestra region es que el camion sale con un recorrido (casi) determinado, y el puesto de venta decide en el momento cuanto compra segun cuanto cash tiene, devuelve productos, etc. Tomando en cuenta que los paises emergentes tienen y van a tener un crecimiento importante en los proximos anios, consideramos que hay un gran potencial para soluciones como la de CPG.

Espero dentor de unos anios postear que el «investment theory se cumplio» 🙂

Read Full Post »

virus en facebook?

Hoy creo que me comi un virus en facebook, la verdad es que no se que efecto podra haber tenido, espero que nada ya que no uso windows ni explorer ;). Puede que me hayan robado el password de facebook pero ya lo cambie.

Aca hay un link sobre el tema:http://news.lalate.com/2009/05/22/whitemartbe-check-whitemart/

 

En fin, les cuento lo que me paso asi no les pasa, recibi un mail IGUALITO a los de facebook, decia:

===================

Michael sent you a message.

Subject: Hi

«Look at whitemart.be»

To reply to this message, follow the link below:

==================

Todo igual a los mensajes de facebook, parecia venir de mi amigo Michael, y como me hablo en ingles con el, podia ser cierto. En fin clickee, me pidio el password de facebook (como siempre), y despues me mando a la nada. Espero que el ser MACero me haya salvado

Read Full Post »

Finalmente estamos autorizados a publicarlo, algun lector ya sabia o habia escuchado algun rumor, el asunto es que Interactive Networks, empresa del portafolio de Prosperitas, fue adquirida por Geodesic, una empresa india del mismo rubro.

Creo que es un evento importantisimo no solo para Prosperitas, sino para toda la comunidad emprendedora uruguaya, ya que es el primer caso de una empresa que redondea el ciclo: recibe inversion de un VC local, y termina siendo adquirida por un comprador estrategico. Lo que muestra que el modelo de VC funciona tambien en estas latitudes.

Aqui hay unos links de la repercusion que tuvo:

http://finance.yahoo.com/news/Geodesic-Announces-bw-15275601.html?.v=1

http://www.reuters.com/article/pressRelease/idUS103762+18-May-2009+BW20090518

Personalmente, fue una experiencia super interesante, negociar una venta de una empresa con gente super diferente (realmente fue una experiencia bastante rara, ahora saben que anduve haciendo hace unos meses en Mumbai)

Aqui abajo pongo el PR de Prosperitas:

 

Prospéritas anuncia la adquisición de Interactive Networks, empresa de su portafolio por parte de Geodesic Systems.

 

MONTEVIDEO, Uruguay –19 de mayo de 2009– Prospéritas Capital Partners anunció hoy la adquisición de Interactive Networks por parte de Geodesic Limited (BSE: 503699, NSE: GEODESIC), proveedor líder en el mercado de mensajería instantánea para celulares y computadoras, VoIP, SMS sobre IP, Radio y Video en Internet. Pablo Brenner, socio de Prospéritas afirmó: “Estamos muy contentos de anunciar esta transacción; es nuestra primera salida de una empresa de nuestro portafolio, y es una clara demostración que el modelo de Venture Capital funciona en nuestra región.”

 

Interactive Networks, con sede en Montevideo, Uruguay, provee soluciones de mensajería global y colaboración, como plataformas de IM (mensajería instantánea) que permiten a los operadores móviles ofrecer a sus clientes servicios de mensajería instantánea, estableciendo conversaciones bidireccionales con cualquier teléfono móvil en su red a través de servicios SMS o MMS (mensaje multimedia). Interactive Networks podrá entonces expandir su gama de productos para operadores de telefonía móvil, mediante la inclusión de los productos de Geodesic en el área de entretenimiento y comunicaciones.

 

Pablo Salomón, CEO de Interactive Networks, afirmó: “Geodesic es una empresa ideal para unir fuerzas con nosotros. Compartimos la visión de proveer servicios móviles de última generación, aprovechando el rápido crecimiento en la demanda de servicios de mensajería instantánea y redes sociales móviles. La inversión de Prospéritas en Diciembre 2006 permitió a Interactive Networks enfocarse en estas metas a largo plazo y en la entrada a mercados estratégicos. Ahora, como parte de Geodesic, el equipo de investigación y desarrollo ubicado en Montevideo ejecutará proyectos desafiantes, de mayor tamaño,   para consumidores alrededor del mundo. Para enfrentar este desafío, estaremos contratando a los mejores de desarrolladores y gerentes.” concluye el Ing. Salomón.

 

Arvind Venkateswaran, Vicepresidente y Gerente General de Geodesic, afirmó: “Esta transacción con Interactive Networks complementa a Geodesic con un equipo de desarrollo que aporta extensa experiencia en VAS móvil, y que nos ayudará a expandir nuestra participación en el mercado.”

 

Los clientes de mensajería instantánea móvil de Interactive Networks permiten a los operadores móviles ofrecer una experiencia completa en mensajería instantánea a los suscriptores, accesible a través de dispositivos móviles, permitiendo a los usuarios enviar y recibir mensajes de texto, de voz, fotos, y mucho más. La empresa ha implementado su solución con 12 de los mayores Carriers a través de América del Sur, África  y Asia.

La adquisición de Interactive Networks ayudará a Geodesic a incrementar su participación más allá de India, Europa, Asia y USA, hacia América del Sur y África. Bajo términos del acuerdo, Interactive Networks se transformará en una subsidiaria 100% perteneciente a Geodesic.

Sobre Interactive Networks

Basada en Montevideo, Uruguay, ha desarrollado y vende soluciones innovadoras de mensajería instantánea desde 1999. La empresa se especializa en soluciones de IM seguras para empresas, soluciones Internet con marca privada y para operadores móviles

 

Interactive Networks recibió en Diciembre de 2006 inversión por parte de Prospéritas Capital Partners.

 

Para más información sobre Interactive Networks, ver: www.interactiveni.com.

 

 

Sobre Geodesic

Geodesic es una empresa innovadora en productos de software enfocados en Información, Comunicación y Entretenimiento para telefonía celular y computadoras. Con sede en Mumbai, India, la empresa cuenta con una serie de productos galardonados (Mundu) entre los que se incluye soluciones para mensajería instantánea Voice-over-IP, y radio por Internet. La empresa cotiza en la Bolsa de India (National Exchange and Bombay Stock Exchange) y cuenta con oficinas en Mumbai y Bangalore en India, USA (Silicon Valley), Inglaterra, Suecia, Mauricio, Alemania y Hong Kong.

 

Para más información sobre Geodesic Limited, ver: www.geodesic.com.

 

 

Sobre Prospéritas

Prospéritas Capital Partners es la primera administradora de fondos de capital de riesgo de Uruguay, creada y gerenciada por un grupo de individuos que comparten la visión de que existe en el Uruguay una nueva clase emprendedora de proyectos. Invierte en empresas y proyectos que, al aportarles capital fresco y know how gerencial puedan crear valor para sus emprendedores e inversores.

 

Por más información sobre Prospéritas Capital Partners, ver: www.prosperitascp.com.

Read Full Post »

Older Posts »